The author considers the various 100% Reserve plans that have appeared since the interwar period and have since then been adapted, but never implemented as such. He then highlights their common features as well as their differences and exposes the criticisms voiced against them. Overall, the 100% Reserve reform does not appear as a meaningful opportunity to improve the functioning of banking systems. However, the reform is, in some respects, getting more topical.
100% Reserve – also called Full-Reserve – plans have appeared in the interwar period and have since then been adapted, in response either to criticisms or to changing circumstances. In all formulations of those schemes, Government liabilities (cash, central bank reserves and short-term Treasuries) back banks’ sight deposits or at least some of them. This is in contrast with current so-called “fractional reserve banking” in which, as a result of reserve requirements imposed by the central bank, reserves back only a small fraction of sight deposits.
The first part of the paper briefly presents the various plans that have emerged, highlighting the context in which they were formulated as their main common features and differences. The second part exposes the numerous criticisms voiced against its different formulations. The third part shows that the 100% Reserve reform is becoming topical. The fourth part concludes.
In chronological order of appearance, one can distinguish six main streams:
Table 1 below summarizes the main differences between the various 100% reserve plans.
Table 1: Main differences in 100% Reserve plans
Chicago Plan | Deposited currency | Narrow Banking | Limited Purpose Banking | Benes & Kumhof | Sovereign Money | ||
Objectives |
Ambition and scope | Limited | Wide | Limited | Wide | Wide | Wide |
Role of public finance | Limited (except Fisher, 1936) | Insignificant | Insignificant | Insignificant | Essential | Essential | |
Control of money | Important | Unimportant | Important | Irrelevant | Essential | Essential | |
Implement- ation |
Reduction of moral hazard | Deposit insurance unnecessary or scope limited | Increase in bank capital requirements | Deposit insurance unnecessary or scope limited | Increase in bank capital requirements | None | None |
Role of banks | Changed | Changed | Changed | Profoundly changed | Profoundly changed | Profoundly changed | |
Role of central bank (apart from provision of reserves) | Can keep some sight deposits | Can keep some sight deposits | Unchanged | Unchanged | Keeps all sight deposits/Finances the economy | Keeps all deposits/Finances the budget | |
Conduct of monetary policy | Marginally changed | Marginally changed | Marginally changed | Marginally changed |
Profoundly changed | Profoundly changed |
100% Reserve has been criticized by academics from the beginning, including in their own camp. I distinguish between the doubts expressed on the validity of the analysis on one hand, and some undesirable consequences of plans on the other.
Regarding the validity of the analysis, critiques have underlined technical but also more fundamental limits.
Some undesirable consequences of 100% Reserve plans would warrant adjustments, complements or closer examination. Others cast doubt on the merits of the whole project.
In spite of the criticisms it has raised, 100% Reserve could get more topical in the coming years as a result of private sector, central bank, and political initiatives.
Addressing the topic of 100% Reserve is fraught with difficulties of two sorts: there is heterogeneity in the approach and most of these formulations lack a well-defined and commonly used analytical framework. This lack of an analytical framework contrasts with more organized schools of thought, such as New Keynesianism, and with presentations of a final organization, which often go into details, as in descriptions of a Utopia, with Dyson et al. (2016) providing the best example. It also contrasts with strong policy prescriptions, such as the systematic backing of all sight deposits with Government liabilities, in all plans except DC, or the creation of reserves essentially to finance public spending in SM.
In this paper, I present the various 100% Reserve plans. I show that there are more differences than common features between them. Furthermore, several features make B&K and SM distinct from other plans whereas LPB appears as a “radicalization” of the CP and NB. DC is original to the extent that it is “à la carte”. I also review the criticisms of 100% Reserve, discuss them and add my own comments. Some of these criticisms have led to alterations of the original framework, notably with a shift of emphasis from money control, characteristic of the CP, to financial stability and moral hazard considerations, put forward in NB and LBP, whereas B&K and SM shift the emphasis back to the creation of money.
Overall, the 100% Reserve reform does not appear as an opportunity to improve the functioning of banking systems. In fact, those systems have already undergone a deep reform following the Great Financial Crisis and have recently demonstrated their resilience to systemic shocks during the Covid-19 crisis. However, SM could easily turn into a calamity. Fortunately, the variant of 100% Reserve that is becoming topical is rather DC, the one among 100% Reserve plans least susceptible of upsetting banking intermediation, and it appears as a by-product of other projects, such as the issuance of a CBDC, rather as an end in itself. More specifically, I suggest that 100% Reserve, issuing a CBDC, exiting QE and public debt repayment are issues that could become intertwined in the future.
Adrian T., Mancini-Griffoli T. (2019), “The rise of digital money”, IMF Note, 19/001, July, https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/fintech-notes/Issues/2019/07/12/The-Rise-of-Digital-Money-47097.
Bacchetta P. (2018), “The sovereign money initiative in Switzerland: an economic assessment”, Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics, 154(3), 1-16.
Benes J. and Kumhof M. (2012), “The Chicago Plan Revisited”, IMF Working Paper, WP/12/202, https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2012/wp12202.pdf.
Chamley C., Kotlikoff L. J., Polemarchakis H. (2012), “Limited Purpose Banking – Moving from “Trust Me’’ to “Show Me’’ Banking”, American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 102(3), 113-119.
Cochrane (2014), “Toward a Run-Free Financial System”, in M. N. Baily and J. B. Taylor (ed.), Across the Great Divide: New Perspectives on the Financial Crisis, Chapter 10, Hoover Institution, Stanford University, https://ideas.repec.org/h/hoo/bookch/8-10.html.
Committee on Financial Services of the House of Representatives (2020), Memorandum on “Inclusive Banking During a Pandemic: Using FedAccounts and Digital Tools to Improve Delivery of Stimulus Payments”, https://www.congress.gov/116/meeting/house/110778/documents/HHRG-116-BA00-20200611-SD002.pdf.
Diamond D., Dybvig P. (1983), “Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity”, Journal of Political Economy, 91(3), 401-419.
Dyson B., Hogdson G., van Lerven F. (2016), Sovereign Money – An Introduction, https://positivemoney.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/12/SovereignMoney-AnIntroduction-20161214.pdf.
Fisher I. (1936), “100% money and the public debt”, Economic Forum, April/June, 406-420, http://realmoneyecon.org/lev2/images/pdfs/100percent_money.pdf.
Friedman M. (1965), A program for monetary stability, https://miltonfriedman.hoover.org/friedman_images/Collections/2016c21/Houghton_1965.pdf.
Goodhart C. (1993), “Can we improve the structure of financial systems?”, European Economic Review, 37, 269-291.
Hart A. G. (1935), “A Proposal for Making Monetary Management Effective in the United States”, Review of Economic Studies, 2(2), 104-116.
Jackson A., Dyson B. (2012), Modernizing Money: Why our Monetary System is Broken and How it Can be Fixed, London, Positive Money.
Jordan (2018), “Why sovereign money would hurt Switzerland”, Swiss National Bank, https://www.snb.ch/en/mmr/speeches/id/ref_20180503_tjn.
Kay J. (2009), Narrow Banking: The Reform of Banking Regulation, CSFI report, https://www.johnkay.com/wp-content/uploads/2009/12/JK-Narrow-Banking.pdf.
Knight F., Cox G., Director A., Douglas P., Hart A., Mints L., Schultz H., Simons H. (1933), Memorandum on Banking Reform, Franklin D. Roosevelt Presidential Library, President’s Personal Fila 431.
Kotlikoff L. (2010), Jimmy Stewart is Dead: Ending the World’s Ongoing Financial Plague with Limited Purpose Banking, Hoboken, NJ, John Wiley & Sons.
Litan R. (1987), What Should banks Do?, Washington, DC, Brookings Institution.
Melachrinos A., Pfister C. (2020), “Stablecoins: A Brave New World?”, 2020, Working Paper 757, Banque de France, https://publications.banque-france.fr/sites/default/files/medias/documents/wp757.pdf.
Pfister C. (2020a), “Central Bank Digital Currency: A Primer”, 2020, SUERF Policy Note 143
Pfister C. (2020b), “100% Reserve: Calamity or Opportunity?”, 2020, Working Paper 786, Banque de France, November, https://publications.banque-france.fr/sites/default/files/medias/documents/wp-786.pdf.
Pfister C., Sahuc J.-G. (2020), “Unconventional Monetary Policies: A Stock-Taking Exercise”, 2020, Revue d’économie politique, 130(2), 136-168.
Pfister C., Valla N. (2020a), “Helicopter money: Panacea, shell game or Faustian pact?”, 2020, Views – The EUROFI Magazine, April, 46, Eurofi Magazine 2020-Valla-Pfister-Helicopter money-Panacea, shell game or Faustian pact.
Pfister C., Valla N. (2020b), “Whoever pays off their debt gets rich”, 2020, Fondapol Note, October, http://www.fondapol.org/en/etudes-en/whoever-pays-off-their-debt-gets-rich/.
Phillips R. J. (1995), “Narrow Banking Reconsidered”, Levy Institute, Policy Brief, 18, http://www.levyinstitute.org/pubs/ppb17.pdf.
Ricks M., Crawford J., Menand L. (2020), “FedAccounts: Digital Dollars”, George Washington Law Review, forthcoming.
Tobin J. (1985), “Financial Innovation and Regulation in Perspective”, Bank of Japan Monetary and Economic Studies, 3(2), 19-29, https://www.imes.boj.or.jp/english/publication/mes/1985/me3-2-3.pdf.
Tobin J. (1987), “The case for Preserving Regulatory Distinctions”, in Proceedings – Economic Policy Symposium – Jackson Hole, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 167-183, https://www.kansascityfed.org/publicat/sympos/1987/s87tobin.pdf.
Wallace N. (1996), “Narrow Banking Meets the Diamond-Dybvig Model”, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Quarterly Review, Winter, 3-13
See for instance the memorandum of the Committee on Financial Services of the House of Representatives (2020) on “Inclusive Banking During a Pandemic: Using FedAccounts and Digital Tools to Improve Delivery of Stimulus Payments”, that itself refers to a similar initiative in the Senate, and Ricks et al. (2020).
This is an adapted version of Pfister (2020b). The views expressed are the author’s and not those of the Banque de France, the Eurosystem, Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne or Sciences Po.