menu
close

Author(s):

Lovisa Reiche | University of Oxford
Aidan Meyler | European Central Bank (ECB)
Christian Gayer | European Commission

Keywords:

Inflation , expectations , uncertainty , consumers

JEL Codes:

Consumers’ inflation expectations play a key role in the monetary transmission mechanism. As such, it is crucial for monetary policymakers to understand what they are and how they are formed. In a recent paper, we introduce the (un)certainty channel as means to shed light on some puzzling aspects of consumers’ reported quantitative inflation perceptions and expectations. These include the apparent overestimation of inflation as well as the observed negative correlation between economic sentiment and inflation expectations. Uncertain consumers are seen more frequently to round their responses to quantitative survey questions, introducing an upward bias. The uncertainty framework helps explain some of the stylised facts of consumers’ inflation expectations, such as their correlation with socio-demographic characteristics and economic sentiment.

Inflation expectations play a key role in the monetary transmission mechanism via the real interest rate channel as well as in wage and price setting processes. Therefore, understanding the nature of economic agents’ inflation expectations and how they are formed is crucial for monetary policymakers.2

In our recent article, we analyse consumers’ one-year ahead inflation expectations using data available from the European Commission Consumer Survey (ECCS) through the lens of uncertainty and address some of the more puzzling stylised facts of these inflation expectations, namely that: (a) the average expectation has tended to be systematically above, although co-moving with, actual inflation; (b) there is an apparent negative correlation between inflation expectations and economic sentiment; (c) there is substantial heterogeneity both across countries and across individuals in terms of the levels of inflation expectations. It should be borne in mind that consumers’ one-year ahead inflation expectations may be more volatile and responsive to actual inflation developments than their more medium or longer-term expectations.

While the link of consumers’ inflation expectations with sociodemographic characteristics and economic sentiment is a well-known feature, the uncertainty framework offers explanations for both the bias in quantitative inflation expectations vis-à-vis actual inflation and their negative relationship with economic sentiment. Previous literature shows that consumers are likely to have higher inflation perceptions and expectations if they are younger, female, have lower levels of formal education and belong to lower income groups.3 Furthermore, consumers that report being in a better financial situation and who have positive expectations about the economy as a whole are associated with lower inflation expectations, and that this also holds when controlling for sociodemographic factors.4 The uncertainty framework helps explain some of the bias as agents who are more uncertain typically report their inflation expectations using round figures (in multiples of five). Furthermore, those who have a negative attitude about the economy as a whole also tend to be more uncertain about the inflation outlook and to report higher inflation expectations. This explains why reported inflation expectations might increase in periods of economic uncertainty.

Looking at consumers’ inflation expectations through the lens of uncertainty

The high frequency of rounding observed in consumers’ quantitative inflation expectations points to uncertainty in reported inflation expectations. A considerable share of euro area consumers reports their quantitative expectations (and perceptions) using round numbers (most notably multiples of 5 and 10), while other consumers report to single digits or even to decimals. The upper panel of Chart 1 shows noticeable peaks at 0%, 5%, 10%, 15% and 20%, with a smaller distribution of respondents reporting to single digits. The modal responses of this latter group are around 2%-3% and thus not as biased as the aggregate numbers.5 According to communications and linguistics theory, round numbers – typically multiples of five or of ten, depending on the context – are frequently used to convey that a quantitative expression should be interpreted as imprecise. We use the “round numbers suggest round interpretations” principle to identify the existence of an uncertainty channel which may influence reported inflation expectations.6 The lower panel of Chart 1 illustrates a considerable shift in the histogram of one-year ahead inflation expectations between December 2020 (when euro area HICP inflation was -0.3%) and December 2021 (when euro area HICP inflation was 5.0), suggesting that both certain and uncertain consumers’ one-year ahead inflation expectations co-move with actual inflation (although the former to a much lesser degree).


Chart 1.
Histogram of responses from -10% to +50%
(y-axis: frequency of response as percentages)

 width=

 width=
Sources: European Commission DG-ECFIN and ECB staff calculations. Note: Histogram constructed at integer level.

What determines whether individuals are (un)certain?

Whether a consumer is certain about price developments can depend on sociodemographic characteristics and/or economic sentiment. To analyse this, we look at the “probability that a consumer is certain” about inflation and try to explain this using a range of sociodemographic and economic sentiment variables.7 The sociodemographic variables include characteristics, such as age, level of formal education, gender and income quartile. In addition, sentiment indicators are used, which take the form of expressed economic opinions on the expected personal financial and general economic situation, a qualitative inflation assessment about inflation in the next 12 months and opinions on unemployment development, as well as on the timing of purchases and savings. On average, and other things being equal, a higher income and higher level of formal education contribute positively to an individual’s estimated probability of being certain. Certainty increases further with age and if respondents are male. At the same time, respondents tend to be less certain if they are more negative about their personal finances, the general economic situation including unemployment and their ability to purchase and save.8 These patterns hold robustly across most time periods and euro area countries in our sample. Chart 2 shows an index of inflation expectations uncertainty over time, where uncertainty is represented by the share of respondents reporting inflation expectations as multiples of five and/or ten (excluding those reporting zero). Noticeable peaks are visible at the time of the global financial crisis in 2008, to a lesser extent around 2011-2013 during period of euro area sovereign debt tensions, after the emergence of the Coronavirus pandemic and again most recently in 2021. Indeed, in April 2020 when the first strong impact from the pandemic affected Europe, there was a decline in the share of consumers reporting inflation expectations of zero or digits from 1%-4%, with noticeable increases in those reporting multiples of five (in particular 10%, 15%, 20%, 25% and 30%).


Chart 2.
Inflation uncertainty index
(y-axis: percent)
 width=
Sources: European Commission DG-ECFIN and ECB staff calculations.
Note: Series shows percentage of respondents reporting inflation expectations in multiples of five or ten (excluding those reporting zero).

Does this (un)certainty framework help explain and foster greater understanding of inflation expectations?

Overall, our model of inflation expectations helps understand the data better. First, we estimate the linear effects of sociodemographic and economic sentiment variables on quantitative inflation expectations.9 Moreover, to control for potentially different macroeconomic environments, actual inflation (HICP), inflation forecasts by Consensus Economics and GDP growth by country and time are incorporated. The (un)certainty framework is then used to split the sample. This makes it possible to show whether the effect of these sociodemographic and economic opinion variables differs between more and less certain consumers.

Dividing the sample into the “certain” and “uncertain” groups explains a large part of the so-called inflation expectation conundrum, i.e. the overestimation of inflation in consumer surveys.10 Applying the above model shows that sociodemographic and sentiment variables have a smaller impact on the inflation expectations of the “certain” group. The difference in inflation expectations between the “certain” and “uncertain” groups is visualised in Chart 3 and contrasted with aggregate estimates. It suggests that the differential in inflation estimates observed between socioeconomic groups and respondents of diverging economic assessments can at least in part be explained by the different levels of certainty these groups of respondents have. These results also hold in a model version that controls for perceptions, given their strong link with expectations. However, it should be noted that even consumers who are certain overestimate inflation. Therefore, the certainty channel should not be considered in isolation from other hypothesised reasons, including psychological aspects of loss aversion, seasonality and the idea that consumers might have in mind different and very heterogeneous baskets (including house prices, for instance) when estimating inflation.11


Chart 3.
Estimated inflation expectations – fitted versus survey results
(y-axis: percentages)
 width=
Sources: European Commission DG-ECFIN, Eurostat and ECB staff calculations.
Notes: This chart displays the estimated one-year inflation expectation calculated for a mean individual (i.e. an individual with mean characteristics in each category) in each country. HICP country weights are then used to aggregate across the euro area. The latest observation is Q4 2021.

We have shown that inflation uncertainty is an important channel that helps shed light on some of the more puzzling aspects of reported quantitative inflation expectations. This framework may be more pertinent in the current environment of heightened geopolitical tensions and energy prices which are volatile and elevated. However, there remain aspects of consumers’ inflation expectations that cannot be addressed using the data considered in our paper. For instance, as we do not observe the same individual over time, it is challenging to understand how expectations are formed and the extent of their economic impact. In the future, the ECB’s Consumer Expectations Survey (CES), which was launched as a pilot in 2020 and has a genuine panel structure, could offer a more in-depth view of consumer expectations over time, their formation and how consumers understand and react to monetary policy.12

 

References

Reiche, L. and Meyler, A. „Making Sense of Consumers’ Inflation Expectations: The role of uncertainty”, European Economy Discussion Paper No. 159, European Commission, February 2022.

  • 1.

    The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the ECB, the European Commission or SUERF. The authors are grateful to Carola Binder for sharing her Matlab code used for the Binder (2017) paper. We also acknowledge useful comments and suggestions from members of the Eurosystem Expert Group on Inflation Expectations as well as participants at an internal ECB presentation. All remaining errors are under the full responsibility of the authors.

  • 2.

    Other things being equal, when economic agents anticipate that inflation will increase, they perceive the real interest rate to fall. As a result, they spend more and save less to optimise their consumption and investment over a long horizon. Inflation expectations also play an important role in the wage and price-setting process and are thus an important determinant of future inflation. See, for example, Draghi, M., Introductory Statement, European Central Bank, 22 October 2015 and Yellen, J., “Comments on Monetary Policy at the Effective Lower Bound”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Economic Studies Program, The Brookings Institution, Vol. 49, No 2, Fall, 2018, pp. 573-579.

  • 3.

    For a first assessment (of Swedish consumers), see Jonung, L., “Perceived and Expected Rates of Inflation in Sweden”, The American Economic Review”, Vol. 71(5), 1981, pp. 961-968; and for a more recent overview of the euro area, see Arioli et al. 2016 “EU Consumers’ Quantitative Inflation Perceptions and Expectations: An Evaluation”, European Economy Discussion Paper No. 38, European Commission, November 2016. A study by Bryan, M. and Venkatu, G., “The Demographics of Inflation Opinion Surveys”, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Commentary, October 2001, argues that these differences cannot be explained purely by different consumption baskets across these different socio-economic groups.

  • 4.

    This has been pointed out for Italian consumers in Del Giovane, P., Fabiani, S. and Sabbatini, R., “What’s behind “inflation perceptions”? A survey-based analysis of Italian consumers”, Temi di discussione (Working papers), No 655, Banca d’Italia, January 2008; and for the European level by Ehrmann, M., Pfajfar, D. and Santoro, D., “Consumers’ Attitudes and Their Inflation Expectations”, International Journal of Central Banking, February 2017, pp. 225-259.

  • 5.

    The broad pattern of some consumers rounding to multiples of 5 and others reporting to single digits or decimals has also been observed for US and Japanese data on consumer expectations. For the United States, see Binder, C., “Measuring uncertainty based on rounding: New method and application to inflation expectations”, Journal of Monetary Economics, Elsevier, Vol. 90(C), 2017, pp. 1-12; and for Japan, see Abe, N. and Ueno, Y., “The Mechanism of Inflation Expectation Formation among Consumers”, RCESR Discussion Paper Series, No DP16-1, Hitotsubashi University, March 2016.

  • 6.

    See Binder (2017, op. cit.) and Krifka, M., “Approximate Interpretations of Number Words: A Case for Strategic Communication” in Hinrichs, E. and Nerbonne, J. (eds.), Theory and Evidence in Semantics, Stanford: CSLI Publications, 2009. Consumer inattention has also been used to explain some of the stylised features of observed consumers’ inflation expectations (see, for example, Kamdar, R., “The Inattentive Consumer: Sentiment and Expectations”, Meeting Papers, No 647, Society for Economic Dynamics, 2019, pp. 109-132. However, it is difficult to reconcile inattention with the increased rounding that is observed at times of heightened uncertainty (when consumers should be more attentive than normal).

  • 7.

    If an estimate is a multiple of 5, the respondent is classified as “uncertain”, while all others are classified as being “certain”. This creates a binary variable which allows the probability that a consumer is certain about inflation expectations/perceptions given their characteristics to be estimated. The estimation then follows a maximum likelihood regression using a logit functional form. Potential misclassification in the dependent variable is accounted for, given that individuals may either be certain but still respond in multiples of five, or may be uncertain but reply with a digit that is not a multiple of five. The method is identical to that proposed in Hausman, J., Abrevaya, J. and Scott-Morton, F., “Misclassification of the dependent variable in a discrete response setting”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 87(2), 1998, pp. 239-269.

  • 8.

    In addition, the level of actual inflation (measured by the overall HICP) and GDP growth in the respective time period and geography is included to capture more structural differences in the panel of respondents. It is found that a higher level of actual inflation and the qualitative level of expected inflation reduces overall certainty.

  • 9.

    A simple linear regression framework is used with the response to the two quantitative questions as the dependent variable respectively. This implies an assumption of linear effects which is deemed justified given that individuals respond in rather broad categories and since it facilitates interpretation of the results.

  • 10.

    A study by Abildgren, K. and Kuchler, A, “Revisiting the inflation perception conundrum”, Journal of Macroeconomics, Vol. 67, 2021) describes the issue of overestimation bias in inflation perceptions and expectations across countries and time periods, and suggests various explanations. The term “inflation perceptions conundrum” is coined in that article but is also found here to be equally applicable in the context of expectations.

  • 11.

    For a summary of the available literature, see Abildgren and Kuchler (2021, op. cit.).

  • 12.

    For more information, see the ECB Consumer Expectations Survey.

About the authors

Lovisa Reiche

Lovisa Reiche is a graduate student at the University of Oxford where she is working on the role of gender roles in inflation expectations and central bank communication. Prior to her studies she held a position as Trainee in the Prices and Costs Division of the DG Economics at the European Central Bank.

Aidan Meyler

Aidan Meyler is a Senior Lead Economist in the Prices and Costs Division at the European Central Bank. Recently he was co-secretary to an Expert Group on Inflation Expectations, which provided input into the ECB’s monetary policy strategy review. He also leads the team working on the ECB Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF) and is a member of the ECB Corporate Telephone Survey (CTS) and Consumer Expectations Survey (CES) team.

Christian Gayer

Christian Gayer is head of the sector “Business and consumer surveys and short-term forecasts” in the European Commission’s Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs. He is Council member of the Centre for International Research on Economic Tendency Surveys (CIRET). He has worked as economist in the Commission’s DG ECFIN since 2004 on changing assignments, including business cycle analysis, economic policy coordination in the framework of the Commission’s European Semester and tax policy analysis. Christian holds a doctorate degree in economics from the University of Bochum.

More on these topics

Tags: