menu
close

Author(s):

Elga Bartsch | BlackRock
Jean Boivin | BlackRock
Stanley Fischer | BlackRock
Philipp Hildebrand | BlackRock

Keywords:

Central banks , fiscal policy , policy coordination , helicopter money , modern monetary theory , MMT , monetary financing , going direct , interest rates , effective lower bound , reversal rate , standing emergency fiscal facility , inflation target , price-level target , yield curve control , negative interest rates , inflation-linked bonds , real assets , inflation

JEL Codes:

E5 , E6 , E52 , E63 , E42

Macroeconomic policy has undergone a revolution in just three months. But without proper guardrails and a clear exit strategy, we believe it is a slippery slope.

Summary

  • Macroeconomic policy has gone through nothing short of a revolution in just three months. The policy response is on a completely different scale compared with the global financial crisis (GFC). Not only has the response been faster and the scale greater than at any moment in peacetime history, but core tenets of global policy frameworks and financial markets have been fundamentally transformed.
  • There are three main aspects to this revolution. First, the new set of policies are explicitly attempting to “go direct” – bypassing financial sector transmission and instead finding more direct pipes to deliver liquidity to households and businesses. Second, there is an explicit blurring of fiscal and monetary policies. Third, government support for companies comes with stringent conditions, opening the door to unprecedented government intervention in the functioning of financial markets and in corporate governance.
  • This policy revolution was inevitable given that the monetary policy space was insufficient to respond to a significant, let alone a dramatic, downturn. We discussed this in our paper Dealing with the next downturn in August 2019 We have crossed the Rubicon in terms of fiscal and monetary policy coordination. As central banks are increasingly implementing fiscal policies, they are becoming even more vulnerable to political interference and pressure.
  • Without proper guardrails and a clear exit strategy, it is unclear how policymakers are going to put the genie back into the bottle. There will already be a need for central banks to absorb much of the debt issued by governments for some time to avoid an uncontrolled rise in long-term yields. And at that point, what will prevent governments from financing new spending in the same way? This opens the door to uncontrolled deficit spending with commensurate monetary expansion and ultimately inflation.
  • A clear exit strategy is required. One approach we laid out is a Standing Emergency Financing Facility (SEFF), a framework in which the exit from the joint monetary-fiscal policy effort is explicitly determined by the inflation outlook. An orderly exit could be very difficult without an ex-ante commitment to a governance framework. And to be credible, this exit decision will need to be independently controlled by the central bank.
  • Many of these policy-related risks would be mitigated if the economy and markets quickly return to a more normal environment. But the longer heavy policy lifting lasts, the more that ad-hoc policy coordination will raise fundamental questions about the functioning of financial markets and the distortions of government interventions – and who truly bears the financial risks associated with monetary policy innovations and corporate bailouts.
  • The policy revolution is key in the near-term to ensure that this real shock doesn’t morph into a financial crisis. We see implementation risks as well as the potential for policy fatigue. A German high court ruling threatened European Central Bank independence earlier this year, and the European recovery fund still needs to navigate through national parliaments. In the U.S., partisan politics in an election year has so far prevented a follow-up on the fiscal stimulus to cushion the pandemic’s impact.
  • A change towards a higher inflation regime is a risk in the medium term, with the lack of a clear exit strategy risking a de-anchoring of inflation expectations in an environment where deglobalization and re-regulation could push costs higher.
  • Given that going direct implies relying less on lower interest rates, portfolio rebalancing and inflating asset price values to deliver stimulus, the playbook of 2008 and its aftermath doesn’t apply. So on its own, this policy revolution is unlikely to be the prelude of a decade-long, policy-fueled bull market for risk assets.

Serious fiscal support
Global fiscal spending and loan guarantees as a share of GDP, 2020
 width=
Sources: BlackRock Investment Institute and finance ministries, June 2020. Notes: The chart shows actual and expected fiscal spending measures and actual loan guarantees across selected developed market economies. We add an area of potential increase to the U.S. loan guarantee bar because the structure of the U.S. programs means they can be scaled to be larger than what has been formally announced. Euro area data is the weighted average of the EMU4 (France, Italy, Germany, Spain). Forward looking estimates may not come to pass.

Unprecedented speed and size

We have witnessed a revolution in macroeconomic policy in response to the coronavirus shock. The speed and size of the response has been greater than at any other moment in peacetime history. The core tenets of global policy frameworks and markets have been fundamentally transformed.

The scale of the fiscal policy response has surpassed the GFC in terms of discretionary fiscal stimulus and government guarantees. See the Serious fiscal support chart above. Fiscal policy mobilization on such a scale has not been seen since World War II. And in some cases, the fresh round of emergency stimulus comes on top of already sizeable budget deficits and steep upward trajectories in public debt.

The increase in “traditional” quantitative easing (QE) – central bank asset purchases – over the past few months is already projected to be slightly above the size of the Federal Reserve’s three QE programs from 2009 to 2014 combined. The additional credit facilities via a range of special purpose vehicles (SPVs) bring the current policy action to more than twice the size of what the Fed did over five years during the GFC. The ECB’s response is approaching two thirds of the balance sheet expansion during the GFC and beyond. See the Unprecedented action chart further below.

The policy response during the GFC forced policy innovations that were seen as a revolution at the time: forward-guidance, QE, negative rates, and funding for lending programs to promote bank lending. See the table. These unconventional policies worked mostly by lowering short- and long-term interest rates – and they also worked through the financial system, affecting the non-financial private sector indirectly. Some of these policies started to blur the distinction between fiscal and monetary policy. Examples are the funding for lending programs (UK), central bank purchases of equity (Japan) and corporate debt (euro area) – as well as the introduction of yield curve control targeting a range for long-term yields (Japan). Yet this blurring still only occurred at the fringes of the policy envelope.

The policy revolution is now taking on a new dimension, with global policy frameworks being redesigned in real time as specific needs arise without much of an institutional framework. We spell out the three main aspects of this revolution below.

New tools in the box
Major central bank policy tools
 width=
Source: BlackRock Investment Institute and central banks, June 2020. Notes: The table shows which major central banks have adopted or are considering different “unconventional” policies. FX swap lines are an agreement between two central banks to exchange currencies. Regulatory forbearance is where central banks state that commercial banks may eat into capital and liquidity buffers to boost liquidity. Direct lending to public authorities is direct cash transfers from the central bank to government to finance spending.

Unchartered territory

The policy revolution has three main parts. First, the new policies are explicitly attempting to “go direct” – bypassing financial sector transmission and finding more direct pipes to deliver liquidity to a larger set of entities. These include businesses, households and foreign central banks. This is in return for a broader set of collateral such as corporate bonds and bank loans, up to and including the Fed’s Main Street facilities. The ECB and the Bank of Japan had already made baby-steps in that direction, but all central banks are now moving into unchartered territory. The U.S. and UK fiscal authorities are explicitly backing this type of central bank lending and in turn are starting to rely on direct borrowing from the central bank at the local government level. The chart below shows how important these direct policy instruments have become relative to the traditional unconventional toolkit. In the euro area, the main innovation is the pandemic emergency purchase programme (PEPP) that allows the ECB to buy government debt out of proportion to euro area country shareholdings in the bank. One consequence: going direct relies less on lower interest rates, portfolio rebalancing and inflating asset price values to deliver stimulus. So on its own, this policy revolution is unlikely to be the prelude of a decade-long, policy-fueled bull market for risk assets as we saw after the GFC.

The second aspect of this revolution is the explicit blurring of fiscal and monetary policies. The policy instruments represented by the green areas in the top chart below all involve credit risk that is explicitly backed by the U.S. Treasury. This is fiscal policy working through a Fed instrument. Boundaries have also been blurred in the use of monetary policy to keep interest rates low – buying government debt as fiscal spending surges. Aside from the few places where it is explicitly presented as yield curve control, large or even unlimited asset purchase programs are tied to maintaining low government bond yields. Temporary monetary financing has been made explicit in the UK. The third aspect of the policy revolution is the stringent conditionality around dividend payouts, share buybacks and executive compensation imposed on companies taking government support. This opens the door to unprecedented government intervention in financial market functioning and corporate governance.

Unprecedented action
Contributions to Fed and ECB balance sheets, in USD billions and EUR billions, 2008-2020
 width=
 width=
Source: BlackRock Investment Institute, Fed and ECB, with data from Haver Analytics, September 2020. Notes: The top chart shows what the Fed’s balance sheet could look like by the end of 2020 with the new facilities launched in the past two months compared with March 6 – just before it began its interventions. The balance sheet at the end of 2020 is based on estimates made by BlackRock’s Global Fixed Income economics team. These projections are based on data from the Fed’s H.4.1 (balance sheet) release and on the structure of the Fed’s facilities found on the Fed website. The purchase pace of securities is listed on the New York Fed website. The estimates also assume that the Fed will increase its planned support for its Paycheck Protection Program loan facility and expand its support for states and municipalities by several hundred billion dollars compared with the initial announcements. By comparison, the Fed pledged as much as $2.3 trillion in loans to support the economy in its April 9 announcement. Estimates of the expected increase and December 2020 totals are rounded. The funding facilities (green bars in top chart) are funded with credit loss protection provided by the U.S. Treasury and lending by the Fed. These programs also include the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Program and Municipal Liquidity Facility. The bottom chart shows the ECB’s comparable balance sheet expansion. PEPP is the Pandemic Emergency Purchase Programme, PSPP is the Public Securities Purchase Programme, CSPP is the Corporate Securities Purchase Programme, LTROS and TLTROS are (Targeted) Long-Term Refinancing Operations and the SMP is the Securities Market Programme. Forward looking estimates may not come to pass.

Historic labor market support

The labor market is one area experiencing an unprecedented amount of government intervention. There is a stark difference in approach on the two sides of the Atlantic. The U.S. is relying mostly on beefed-up unemployment insurance (UI) and Europe on short-time work programs. The former aims to help people who have lost their job, and the latter aims to keep people in work by paying companies to keep employees on at reduced hours. The policy choices matter in terms of the near-term recovery and any long-term scarring. The size of the U.S. and European interventions are similar, but they could have very different consequences for the distribution of lost income between consumers and companies.

The difference between the approaches lies in who bears the risk of the policy falling short, the impact on company-specific, intangible human capital and future employment dynamics. The reliance on short-time work programs has historically correlated with the strictness of labor market regulations. These programs offer greater flexibility to reduce hours worked without redundancies, equally affecting all workers in a company and allowing companies to operate at reduced capacity. And they avoid the costs of firing and re-hiring. U.S. unemployment benefits currently are slightly more generous than short-time work benefits (see the chart on the right below), mainly due to a pandemic top-up that expired in July. Workers in short-time work programs keep social security contributions and healthcare coverage, and may be better off in the long run than those on unemployment benefits as a result.

Unemployment is more disruptive even in lightly regulated labor markets – such as in the U.S. – and company-specific human capital can get lost through the churning of the workforce. It is harder to rehire than to increase the number of hours worked – especially as uncertainty may remain as economies open up. Those labor markets relying mostly on letting staff go could take longer to recover. And the risk of a cash crunch as payments work through the system lies with the worker, not the company. This is important given the temporary nature of the stepped-up benefits in the U.S. and in the UK (end of October). Cliff edges are clear. U.S. consumers are more likely to bear the brunt of the coronavirus crisis, while in Europe companies might have to face the decision on layoffs later. In the U.S., which has introduced payroll support such as the Paycheck Protection Program (PPP) for businesses, the terms – capped at 24 of costs – are less generous than in Europe. And there were some teething problems to begin with.

Historically, the U.S. labor market has been able to weather downturns better than those in the euro area. Thanks to its flexibility it recovered more quickly and avoided many of the long term-increases in the NAIRU (non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment) seen in the euro area until the 2000s. The rise in U.S. unemployment could become more persistent given the size of the coronavirus shock, however, and raise issues associated with long-term job losses. Short-time work programs, by contrast, smooth the labor market shock more effectively than unemployment insurance even assuming comparable replacement rates – provided the shock is short lived. At the same time, such programs might slow some of the longer-term structural changes that could result from the coronavirus pandemic, and make the economy less flexible, innovative and competitive as a result. The two approaches are clearly very different.

Jobless jump
Unemployment levels and labor market policies, February and June 2020
 width=
Sources: BlackRock Investment Institute, U.S. Small Business Association, UK Revenue and Customs, UK Treasury, European Trade Union Confederation, OECD, with data from Haver Analytics, June 2020. Notes: The orange bars in the left chart show the official unemployment rate for the U.S., euro area (EMU4) and UK. The yellow bar represents the estimated proportion of the U.S. workforce on the PPP. We calculate how many workers could be supported by the loans by assuming they are paid an average wage (taken from pre-crisis data) through the eight-week period for which they are eligible for paycheck protection. The green bars show the share of the workforce registered for short time work or furlough programs. The pink bars on the right show the share of pay that is paid by UI in the U.S., and furlough schemes in the euro area and UK. For workers in the U.S. covered by the PPP, the replacement rate is 100%. Those who are then laid off would receive UI benefit at the replacement rate shown by the dark and light pink bar. In the U.S., the additional pandemic top-up payment expires after July but may be extended. The pink bars for the euro area and UK show replacement rates of conventional unemployment insurance.

A point of no return

This global policy revolution was inevitable and is largely going in the direction that we discussed last August. We also stressed at the time that closer coordination between monetary and fiscal policy would be a slippery slope without proper guardrails and a clear exit strategy. The risk now is that we start sliding down that slope. We have crossed the Rubicon in terms of fiscal and monetary policy coordination. Central banks are becoming ever more vulnerable to political interference and pressure as they implement policies that have clear fiscal dimensions. Currently the Fed is implementing credit support policy (as a banker), but the Treasury owns the credit risk (as the ultimate owner of the special purpose vehicle). Who gets to decide when to stop and on what basis?

The blurring of the boundaries can be illustrated by comparing net government bond issuance to central bank purchase programs. See the charts below. In the case of Japan, the formal adoption of yield curve control has pushed BOJ purchases well above net issuance in the past few years. The same has happened in the euro area as the ECB has tried to contain sovereign spreads since 2015. Now the Fed has dramatically picked up the pace of its bond purchases to keep up with the Treasury’s net issuance. If purchases climb above net issuance, this could be interpreted as a more deliberate attempt to put a lid on bond yields. Observing a closer correlation between the pace of purchases and the pace of net issuance – as seen in the UK in the past – would be a further indication of boundaries becoming blurred.

Blurring the boundaries
Government bond issuance and central bank bond buying, 2005-2020
 width=
Source: BlackRock Investment Institute, ECB, BOE, UK Debt Management Office, Japan Securities Dealers Association, Bank of Japan, US Federal Reserve and the US Bureau of Public Debt., with data from Haver Analytics, June 2020. Notes: These charts show the net issuance of government bonds in the four economies, and the government bond buying programs of the central banks in those economies. In the euro area, the PSPP and PEPP are the ECB’s Public Securities Purchase Programme and the Pandemic Emergency Purchase Programme.

The way out

It’s important to have a clear exit strategy. Otherwise, it is not clear how policymakers would put the genie back in the bottle. There a is need for continued monetary policy coordination to avoid an uncontrolled rise in long-term yields. This implies that central banks will absorb new debt issued by governments. This amounts to de-facto debt monetization if it’s done on a large scale and over a long period – even without public entities directly tapping the central bank. Without an exit strategy from the government debt purchases or from yield curve control, it is not clear what check and balance prevents full-blown uncontrolled fiscal spending (for example, Modern Monetary Theory).

There is a clear need for an institutional framework to enable an exit. We have suggested one that explicitly ties the exit from the joint monetary-fiscal policy effort to the inflation outlook and financial stability assessment. This is what our Standing Emergency Financing Facility (SEFF) – sketched out below – could achieve. It needs an ex-ante commitment from central banks and governments to an institutional framework guiding policy coordination. If this institutional void is not filled, markets could see high inflation outcomes as we did under Fed chairs during the 1970s. Getting inflation under control would require implementing painful policies such as former Fed Chair Paul Volcker’s playbook in the early 1980s: high interest rates to dampen inflation.

These risks could be particularly acute in the in U.S. where the ad-hoc policy coordination is happening at a time when the Fed has become more explicitly part of the political debate and is under overt political pressure. In the UK, the radical shift in the BOE stance on debt monetization in the space of just a few days in April does not convey the impression of a robust policy framework, either.

Many of these policy-related risks can be mitigated if the current shock is only temporary, and the economy and markets quickly return to a more normal environment. But the longer heavy policy lifting lasts, the more the ad-hoc policy coordination will raise fundamental questions about the functioning of financial markets and the distortions from government interventions – and who bears the financial risks in the end. This concerns not only the financial risks associated with monetary policy innovations, but also the corporate bailouts and the accompanying restrictions.

One important investment corollary of the current policy revolution is the potential for an eventual shift in the inflation regime – not now given the near-term deflationary outlook but further down the road. A change in the central bank reaction function on the back of blurred boundaries between monetary and fiscal policy could create a greater inflationary bias and an upward shift in inflation expectations. Even if consumer price inflation does not react much to changes in capacity utilization or the unemployment rate, it is important to recognize that inflation expectations are a separate driver of inflation in their own right – and can become self-fulfilling.

Deficit spending, deglobalization and reregulation could all contribute to higher costs once the initial deflationary shock from the giant demand shortfall dissipates. This could translate into higher consumer price inflation. In the near-term, the downside risks to the inflation outlook are likely to dominate as the size of the negative demand shock – with consumers taking time to feel safe enough to return to shops or to leisure activities depending on new virus cases – may outweigh the negative supply shock. This means some slack will open-up on the back of the collapse in activity. Median growth forecasts from Reuters imply that it could take a few years to close the output gap. Absorbing higher costs in already squeezed profit margins becomes increasingly difficult. Output prices will likely be raised as a result.

Over the medium-term, permanent damage to production could cause inflation pressure to build earlier in the cycle than otherwise. High debt levels and implicit yield curve controls to maintain debt stability might force monetary policy to become more tolerant of inflation, potentially causing inflation expectations to become unanchored.

In action
Stylized impact of SEFF on yields and prices
 width=
Sources: BlackRock Investment Institute, August 2019. Notes: These stylized charts show the hypothetical impact of a temporary increase in fiscal stimulus financed by the central bank, as reflected in the SEFF funding (red line in top chart). The other red lines show the impact on the inflation trend relative to the inflation target (dotted line on bottom chart) and on the long-term sovereign bond yield (middle chart). The yellow lines show the hypothetical outcome if there is no stimulus. For illustrative purposes only. There is no guarantee that any forecasts made will come to pass.

Policy implementation risks

We are watching several signposts for assessing the risk asset outlook during the coronavirus shock. First is how successful countries are at restarting activity and reducing social costs of the lockdown while controlling the virus spread. Second is how the joint fiscal-monetary policy is being delivered through successful and timely policy execution – especially for go-direct policies that put money into hands of entities that need help bridging cash flow shortfalls. Third is tracking whether cracks are appearing on the balance sheets of cash-constrained entities while keeping an eye on financial market functioning and plumbing.

We see policy execution risks cropping up in different places. The euro area is one. The German constitutional court decision requiring the ECB or the Bundesbank to justify its government bond purchases to the German government served as a cautionary tale of how execution can potentially be scuppered. This ruling threatened the independence of the ECB – and renewed financial fragmentation within the euro area. The ECB responded to the court and the matter seems settled for now – but we could see further challenges to the more flexible PEPP. The ruling could have put a wrench into the works of the ECB’s “whatever it takes” commitment at a time when effective policy execution was critical to safeguard the economy against damages from the coronavirus shock.

The ruling, which had immediate consequences for the ECB’s monetary policy, has led the European Union’s top court to state that it alone has the power to rule on whether EU bodies are in breach of the bloc’s rules. The dispute is partly a consequence of the blurring of boundaries between monetary and fiscal policies – and particularly problematic in the euro area due to the lack of a joint fiscal authority. The creation of a joint European debt management agency or the creation of so-called eurobonds, issued under the liability of all member states, would require a change in the European Treaty. This would trigger referendums in some countries and remains a controversial issue.

The €750 billion European recovery fund is a step in the right direction toward a common policy response by the EU to the coronavirus crisis. More evolutionary than revolutionary, it is significant for four reasons. First, the funds are intended as grants to member states hit hardest by the crisis, similar to funds distributed by the European Commission to the poorer euro area nations. Second, the overall amount at around 5% of EU GDP is meaningful on its own. Together with the measures agreed at the April EU Summit, the EU policy response announced this year now totals more than €1 trillion. Third, the additional spending is financed via the EU budget, and debt is issued under the standard EU mechanism – helping create a sizable „safe“ asset under the EU. As a result, it does not count towards national debt levels. Fourth, up to 50% of the newly issued debt could be purchased by the ECB under current rules, giving the ECB extra room to manoeuvre.

Policy fatigue is a risk. This is most acute in the U.S., where fiscal support has been delivered via discretionary programs rather than through automatic stabilizers associated with the euro area’s welfare. This means the support can be turned off abruptly – as occurred with the lapse in supplemental unemployment insurance payments. The debate in the U.S. on extending and expanding support for unemployed workers, disrupted businesses, and states and localities has so far succumbed to partisan politics before the November election, though there is still a small possibility of a deal to provide another tranche of aid.

Europe faces its own problems. Both Italy and Spain are governed by potentially unstable coalition governments. Germany’s Merkel oversees a weak coalition and is still planning to step aside. France’s Macron has lost his outright majority in parliament due to defecting lawmakers. And populism remains a potent force in many countries, helping exacerbate a drift toward European fragmentation and geopolitical tensions such as those between the U.S. and China. See the European fragmentation and U.S.-China relations risks on the BlackRock geopolitical risk dashboard.


BlackRock disclosure

This material is reprinted with permission of BlackRock. This material is intended for professional and institutional clients only. The opinions expressed in this reprint are not intended to be relied upon as a forecast, research or investment advice, and is not a recommendation, offer or solicitation to buy or sell any securities or to adopt any investment strategy.

The opinions expressed are as of October 2020 and may change as subsequent conditions vary. The information and opinions contained in this material are derived from proprietary and nonproprietary sources deemed by BlackRock to be reliable, are not necessarily all-inclusive and are not guaranteed as to accuracy. As such, no warranty of accuracy or reliability is given and no responsibility arising in any other way for errors and omissions (including responsibility to any person by reason of negligence) is accepted by BlackRock, its officers, employees or agents. This material may contain ’forward looking’ information that is not purely historical in nature. Such information may include, among other things, projections and forecasts. There is no guarantee that any forecasts made will come to pass. Reliance upon information in this material is at the sole discretion of the reader. You can access the original article here.

Capital at risk: The value of investments and the income from them can fall as well as rise and are not guaranteed. The investor may not get back the amount originally invested.

Past performance is not a reliable indicator of current or future results and should not be the sole factor of consideration when selecting a product or strategy. Changes in the rates of exchange between currencies may cause the value of investments to diminish or increase. Fluctuation may be particularly marked in the case of a higher volatility fund and the value of an investment may fall suddenly and substantially. Levels and basis of taxation may change from time to time.

©2020 BlackRock, Inc. All Rights Reserved. BlackRock® is a registered trademark of BlackRock, Inc., or its subsidiaries in the United States and elsewhere. All other trademarks are those of their respective owners.

  • 1.

    This Policy Note is a partly updated version of „Policy revolution“, BlackRock’s macro and market perspectives issued in June 2020. Please see the disclosure below the article.

  • 2.

    Elga Bartsch – Head of Macro Research, BlackRock Investment Institute
    Jean Boivin – Head of BlackRock Investment Institute
    Stanley Fischer – Senior Advisor, BlackRock
    Philipp Hildebrand – Vice Chairman, BlackRock

About the authors

Elga Bartsch

Elga Bartsch, PhD, Managing Director, heads up economic and markets research at the Blackrock Investment Institute (BII). BII provides connectivity between BlackRock’s portfolio managers, originates economic and market research and publishes insights. Prior to joining BlackRock, Dr. Bartsch was Global Co-Head of Economics and Chief European Economist at Morgan Stanley in London. She started her career as a research associate at the Kiel Institute for the World Economy, a large German economic think-tank where she worked at the President’s office and managed the Advanced Studies in International Economic Policy Research, a post-graduate program in international macroeconomics. Dr. Bartsch has more than 20 years of macro research experience and is a member of the ECB Shadow Council and a trustee of the IFO Institute for economic research. She also served on and chaired the Economic and Monetary Policy Committee of the German Banking Association. Having studied at the University of Hannover and the London School of Economics, Dr. Bartsch graduated with a Master’s degree from Kiel University where she subsequently also completed a PhD.

Jean Boivin

Jean Boivin, PhD, Managing Director, is Global Head of Research for the Blackrock Investment Institute and is a member of the EMEA Executive Committee. His team is responsible for economic and markets research, and for developing the core principles and intellectual property that underpin BlackRock’s approach to portfolio design, such as capital market assumptions and optimization tools. Prior to joining BlackRock, Dr. Boivin served as Deputy Governor of the Bank of Canada and Associate Deputy Finance Minister, serving as Canada’s representative at the G7, G20 and Financial Stability Board. Dr. Boivin has also taught at Columbia Business School and HEC Montreal and has written widely on macroeconomics, monetary policy and finance. Dr. Boivin earned a B.Sc. degree in economics from the Universite de Montreal in 1995, an MA in economics from Princeton University in 1997 and a PhD in economics from Princeton University in 2000.

Stanley Fischer

Stanley Fischer currently serves a Senior Advisor to BlackRock’s Investment Institute (BII). In this role he is a key contributor to BII’s research and to its ongoing dialogue with clients on markets, economics and central bank policy. Prior to joining BlackRock, he held the position of Vice Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System from 2014 to 2017. Prior to his appointment to the Board, Dr. Fischer was governor of the Bank of Israel from 2005 through 2013. From February 2002 to April 2005, Dr. Fischer was Vice Chairman of Citigroup. He served as the First Deputy Managing Director of the International Monetary Fund from September 1994 through August 2001. From January 1988 to August 1990, he was the Chief Economist of the World Bank. From 1977 to 1999, Dr. Fischer was a professor of economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Prior to joining the MIT faculty, Dr. Fischer was an assistant professor of economics and a postdoctoral fellow at the University of Chicago. He has published many articles on a wide variety of economic issues, and he is the author and editor of several scholarly books. Dr. Fischer was born in Lusaka, Zambia. He received his BSc and MSc in economics from the London School of Economics. He received his PhD in economics from the Massachusetts Institute of Technology in 1969.

Philipp Hildebrand

Philipp Hildebrand is Vice Chairman of BlackRock, a member of the firm’s Global Executive Committee, and Chairman of Multi-Asset Strategies (MAS). Philipp has served as a Senior Visiting Fellow at Oxford University’s Blavatnik School of Government and he sits on the School’s International Advisory Board. Until January 2012, he served as Chairman of the Governing Board of the Swiss National Bank (SNB). In that capacity, he was a Director of the Bank for International Settlements (BIS), the Swiss Governor of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and a member of the Financial Stability Board (FSB). In November 2011, the Leaders of the G20 appointed him Vice Chairman of the FSB. Previously, Hildebrand served as Chief Investment Officer of a Swiss private bank and as a partner of Moore Capital Management in London. Between 2006 and 2009, he served as a member of the Strategic Committee of the French Debt Management Office. He began his professional career at the World Economic Forum in Geneva. Mr. Hildebrand earned a BA from the University of Toronto in 1988, a Master’s degree from the Graduate Institute of International Studies in Geneva in 1990, and a DPhil from the University of Oxford in 1994.

More on these topics

Tags: