menu
close

Author(s):

Joachim Nagel | Deutsche Bundesbank

Keywords:

asset purchase programmes , central bank balance sheet , collateral transformation , Eurosystem , euro area , operational framework , monetary policy , monetary policy implementation , money markets , money market activity , money market rate volatility

JEL Codes:

E42 , E43 , E52 , E58

This Policy Note is based on a speech made by the author at the Konstanz Seminar on Monetary Theory and Monetary Policy, 16 May 2024.

In spring 2024, the ECB Governing Council announced changes to its operational framework for implementing monetary policy. Most importantly, the Eurosystem will reduce the spread between the MRO rate and the deposit facility rate from fifty to fifteen basis points as of mid-September 2024. This lowering of the spread will likely keep money market volatility in check, but provides incentives to shift from market to central bank funding. The Eurosystem will monitor this trade-off carefully and will continue to show its capability and flexibility to adapt to changing market conditions.

Introduction

In spring 2024, the ECB Governing Council announced changes to its operational framework for implementing monetary policy.1 I want to discuss how these changes came about, and what they might mean for the future. The note is structured in three parts. First, I will briefly recount how we ended up with the operational framework as it currently stands. Second, I will describe the most important changes that we have decided. And third, I would like to identify a couple of factors that merit close scrutiny over the coming two years until our next scheduled review.

The road to the current operational framework

The ECB Governing Council takes monetary policy decisions based on our monetary policy strategy. And this strategy is centred around our primary objective of maintaining price stability. The purpose of our operational framework is to steer short-term money market rates closely in line with these monetary policy decisions. Or, put differently: Our monetary policy strategy guides us in deciding the appropriate level of short-term interest rates. And the operational framework then enables us to align short-term market rates with this appropriate level.

Before the global financial crisis, many central banks implemented monetary policy using a corridor system. In the case of the Eurosystem, the ECB Governing Council set three interest rates, with specific spreads between them.2

The Eurosystem provided a limited amount of liquidity at the interest rate on the main refinancing operations, the MRO rate. Euro area banks with a remaining deficit of reserves were able to borrow additional amounts overnight at the interest rate on the marginal lending facility, the MLF rate. And euro area banks with an excess of reserves were able to deposit them with the Eurosystem at the interest rate on the deposit facility, the DFR.

However, euro area banks also had the possibility to lend at higher rates than the DFR or to borrow at lower rates than the MLF rate in the interbank market. Banks thus faced an opportunity cost when accessing central bank facilities. This way, the Eurosystem aimed at keeping short-term interest rates in line with the MRO rate.

To support this goal, the Eurosystem estimated the aggregate liquidity needs of the banking sector. The main sources of liquidity needs are euro area banks’ reserve requirements and autonomous factors which are outside the control of the ECB’s monetary policy operations. Somewhat simplified, the autonomous factors comprise banknotes in circulation as well as deposits of euro area governments with the Eurosystem.

The Eurosystem would then provide reserves totalling the estimates of the liquidity needs as part of the weekly main refinancing operations. Euro area banks would place their bids and the Eurosystem supplied the reserves competitively through auctions. To sum up, we operated in a corridor system with scarce reserves and variable rate tenders. The US Federal Reserve System, too, operated with scarce reserves, though they provided liquidity via asset purchases instead of lending operations.3

Things started to change with the global financial crisis.4 Up until the crisis, euro area banks with a surplus of reserves would usually lend them in the interbank market to banks with a deficit of reserves.5 This lending took place to a significant extent by means of unsecured over-the-counter transactions. As reserves were sufficient only on an aggregate basis, the redistribution of reserves was a prerequisite for the scarce reserve regime to function smoothly. This business depended largely on counterparty risks being contained and predictable.

With the onset of the global financial crisis, reserves began to be redistributed less and less. In the market, the supply of reserves declined, while demand spiked, especially from riskier banks. In response, the Eurosystem moved from a system with competitive bidding for a limited supply of reserves in the main refinancing operations to a system with fixed rates and full allotment.

When market funding was not available or too costly, banks with a deficit of reserves now borrowed additional amounts from the Eurosystem. And banks with a surplus of reserves would place them in our deposit facility. This created sizeable amounts of excess liquidity.6 And because of the excess liquidity, short-term interest rates declined well below the MRO rate.

Five years later, faced with a prolonged period of inflation below target, the Eurosystem launched a first series of targeted longer-term refinancing operations (TLTROs) in 2014. These offered banks long-term funding at attractive conditions. Financing volumes rose from up to 425 billion euro provided via TLTRO I to more than 2 trillion euro provided via TLTRO III – equal to about 15% of euro area GDP. Alongside the TLTROs, the Eurosystem also started to buy significantly more debt securities with the launch of the asset purchase programme (APP) in 2014. Securities holdings for monetary policy purposes rose from around 195 billion euro at the end of September 2014 to almost 5 trillion euro, equivalent to almost 40% of euro area GDP, in summer 2022.

Both measures added substantially to the excess liquidity and caused short-term interest rates to decline towards the level of the deposit facility rate. Over time, it was perceived that the Eurosystem had moved gradually from a corridor system to a de facto floor system.7

The Eurosystem’s new operational framework

The Eurosystem discontinued reinvestments under the APP in July 2023. As of the second half of 2024, we have started to run off the pandemic emergency purchase programme (PEPP). And euro area banks have repaid most of the TLTRO volumes. Consequently, excess liquidity has finally started to decline and will continue to do so over the coming years. Excess liquidity peaked at more than 4.6 trillion euro in November 2022. It has since come down by roughly one-third, to about 3.2 trillion euro today.

This shrinking of the balance sheet was long overdue and will free up policy space for the future. It is thus highly welcome. However, it also sparked the question of how the Eurosystem will provide liquidity on a regular basis going forward. And how it intends to steer short-term money market rates closely in line with the Governing Council’s monetary policy decisions.

So what did we decide on in our framework review? I would like to focus on two things: First, we will continue to provide liquidity in the weekly main refinancing operations and three-month longer-term refinancing operations through fixed rate tender procedures, with full allotment, and against a broad set of collateral. Second, and in my eyes most consequentially, we will reduce the spread between the MRO rate and the deposit facility rate from fifty to fifteen basis points as of mid-September 2024. This narrower spread is supposed to incentivise bidding in the weekly operations, so that short-term money market rates are likely to evolve in the vicinity of the deposit facility rate.

In addition to key parameters and features, we agreed on a set of guiding principles for monetary policy implementation, two of which I would like to highlight: First, the effectiveness principle. The main objective of our operational framework is to implement our intended monetary policy stance. This is done by aligning short-term interest rates with our monetary policy decisions. If short-term interest rates fluctuate too heavily, this might blur the signal about the intended monetary policy stance and at some point reduce effectiveness.

Second, the open market economy principle. Our operational framework should be in line with the principle of an open market economy with free competition. This applies, in principle, to all financial market segments affected by monetary policy implementation, notably to bank funding markets. The open market economy principle favours the efficient allocation of resources, an effective price discovery mechanism and the smooth transmission of monetary policy.

Furthermore, we agreed that the framework should be robust, flexible, efficient and, without prejudice to the ECB’s primary objective of price stability, that it should support the general economic policies in the European Union.8

The trade-off between market activity and volatility

The main trade-off we face exists, in my view, between the effectiveness and open market economy principles. Because, unfortunately, keeping fluctuations in money market rates at bay and encouraging money market activity do not necessarily go hand in hand. Providing ample liquidity at a narrow spread between the main refinancing and deposit facility rates may keep the volatility of short-term interest rates in check, but it discourages market activity, especially among banks. And vice versa, providing liquidity at a wider spread encourages market activity, but it might come at the cost of larger fluctuations in short-term interest rates.

We on the ECB Governing Council decided that a spread of fifteen basis points will limit the scope for volatility in market rates, and leave room for banks to seek market-based funding solutions. What should we make of this trade-off between the open market economy principle that intends to encourage market activity and the effectiveness principle that aims at limiting money market volatility?

Let me start with the effectiveness principle. Too much volatility in money market rates might blur the signal about the intended policy stance. What do I mean by that? The ECB Governing Council decides on a specific monetary policy stance because it considers that stance appropriate for achieving price stability in the medium term. Short-term interest rates are an important starting point for monetary policy transmission into broader price developments. They affect medium and long-term market rates, which in turn influence the cost of bank borrowing. And the borrowing costs of households, firms and governments then ultimately have a bearing on output growth and the inflation rate. By implication, rate volatility may become a problem (only) if it adversely affects the transmission mechanism of monetary policy to a relevant extent.

Unfortunately, there is relatively little research on what would happen if short-term interest rates were to fluctuate substantially around the key policy rates. In particular, the ultimate effect on inflation is unclear. Do short-term rate fluctuations affect monetary transmission in a meaningful way? And if so, what degree of fluctuations? Examining this in more detail could deliver valuable input for future policy discussions. And it would help us understand how important it really is to keep rate volatility contained in the pursuit of the primary objective of price stability.

What about the open market economy principle? In our current and future operational framework, all eligible banks can borrow at the same rate, provided they pledge sufficient eligible collateral and fulfil certain minimum criteria concerning their financial soundness. In bank funding markets, by contrast, banks have to pay different interest rates depending on their financial soundness.

In principle, this rate differentiation steers the allocation of funds in the economy, provides incentives for banks to strengthen their balance sheets, and contributes to making the banking system more efficient and stable overall. At the same time, it reduces the burden on the central bank to decide who is a trustworthy counterparty – and increases the responsibility of the market. These benefits of more market activity are rather intangible and thus notoriously difficult to quantify. But I guess everyone can agree that more market-based funding favours an efficient allocation of resources.

Currently, money market participants price most unsecured overnight transactions at a narrow spread of zero to ten basis points. For this segment, the future spread of 15 basis points seems enough to provide economic incentives for some market activity. Most of these transactions currently take place between banks and non-banks. Interbank transactions might need higher spreads. But in the longer-term money market segments, a spread of 15 basis points might risk pricing many transactions out of the market which can still take place at a wider spread.

The narrower spread might have a direct impact on liquidity regulation as well.9 Banking regulation requires euro area banks to fulfil certain liquidity requirements.10 Most importantly, they have to hold a minimum stock of high-quality liquid assets (HQLA) against their net liquidity outflows over the next 30 days. One way to meet these requirements is to borrow reserves from the Eurosystem, which are defined as HQLA, against non-HQLA collateral. In that way, banks transform illiquid and lower-quality assets into high-quality liquid assets in a process known as collateral transformation.

The opportunity cost of this trade is currently 50 basis points: the spread between the main refinancing rate and the deposit facility rate. Banks thus have a solid financial incentive to self-insure against liquidity risk in the market. Lowering the spread to 15 basis points has the potential to reduce the opportunity cost and provide incentives to shift from market to central bank funding.

The good thing is: We have enough time to observe how market activity evolves over the coming years. In particular, we have to evaluate the trade-off between the potential reduction of volatility and less market activity with possibly higher collateral transformation.

Conclusions

While the Eurosystem’s balance sheet will gradually shrink, excess liquidity will remain significant over the coming years. Accordingly, while some volatility cannot be ruled out, short-term money market interest rates are expected to continue evolving in the vicinity of the deposit facility rate.

Over the next two years, we will closely monitor three key aspects until our next scheduled review: First, we will assess the development of money market activity, including in the medium-term segment. Second, we will analyse possible fluctuations of short-term interest rates and their influence on the transmission of monetary policy. And third, we will scrutinise the degree of collateral transformation. In light of the findings, the Eurosystem will continue to show its capability and flexibility to adapt to changing market conditions.

  • 1.

    See Changes to the operational framework for implementing monetary policy (europa.eu).

  • 2.

    See Key ECB interest rates (europa.eu) for details.

  • 3.

    See Kahn, G. (2010), Monetary policy under a corridor operating framework, Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Vol. 95(Q IV), pp. 5-34.

  • 4.

    See Baker, N. and S. Rafter (2022), An International Perspective on Monetary Policy Implementation Systems, Reserve Bank of Australia, Bulletin, June, for an international perspective on the changes in monetary policy implementation after the global financial crisis.

  • 5.

    See Bech, M. and C. Monnet (2017), A search-based model of the interbank money market and monetary policy implementation, Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 164, pp. 32-67, for a theoretical model of the interbank market.

  • 6.

    Excess liquidity equals the sum of excess reserves and deposits in the deposit facility. Excess reserves are deposits by credit institutions on settlement accounts with the central bank that exceed the minimum reserve requirements.

  • 7.

    See Afonso, G. et al. (2023), Monetary Policy Implementation with an Ample Supply of Reserves, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, No 910, for a theoretical discussion.

  • 8.

    See Changes to the operational framework for implementing monetary policy (europa.eu) for details on these four other principles.

  • 9.

    See Bech, M. and T. Keister (2017), Liquidity regulation and the implementation of monetary policy, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 92, pp. 64-77, for a theoretical discussion of the impact of the Basel III liquidity coverage ratio (LCR) on interbank interest rates in an otherwise-standard model of monetary policy implementation.

  • 10.

    Quantitative provisions for liquidity were introduced into European law for the first time by the Capital Requirements Regulation (CRR, Regulation (EU) No 575/2013), in keeping with the Basel liquidity framework.

About the authors

Joachim Nagel

Joachim Nagel has been President of the Deutsche Bundesbank since January 2022. Prior to this, he had already served in management positions at the Bundesbank between 1999 and 2016, including as an Executive Board member from 2010 with responsibility for the Directorates General Markets, Controlling and IT. From 2016 to 2020, he worked for the KfW Group, including as an Executive Board member. In 2020, he moved to the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) where he became Deputy Head of the Banking Department. Dr Nagel studied economics at the University of Karlsruhe and received a doctoral degree in 1997. He also serves as a member of the Governing Council of the ECB, a Governor at the IMF and a member of the BIS Board of Directors.

More on these topics

Tags: